Wage Watchers in Brussels – European Commission focuses on labor market agreements | Hogan Lovells


Antitrust authorities are increasingly focusing on anti-competitive agreements in labor markets. In a recent speech in Rome on 22 October 2021 (“A New Era of Cartel Enforcement”), EU Competition Commissioner Margrethe Vestager underlined that the Commission will increasingly prosecute atypical cartels, including conduct such as wage setting or no-poaching agreements. .

Combined with Vestager’s announcement of a series of searches in the coming months, it is not excluded that Brussels will initiate in the near future the first antitrust procedure for collusion in the HR sector.

Labor market cartel investigations are no longer unfamiliar territory in the world

The European Commission would by no means play a pioneering role in initiating antitrust proceedings concerning anti-competitive agreements in the human resources sector. Internationally, several competition authorities are already far ahead on this point:

  • The US Department of Justice has pursued collusion in the human resources industry for more than a decade, the last time even as a criminal violation. Following an executive order from US President Joe Biden on promoting economic competition, the agency declared this issue a top priority for the Antitrust Division in early October 2021 and has already initiated its first case.
  • The Mexican antitrust authority recently imposed fines of $ 8.8 million in the field of women’s football after the discovery of wage agreements between teams and federations.
  • Over the past year and a half, national antitrust authorities in Europe have also started investigating mutual no-poaching agreements and wage fixing in independent antitrust proceedings and have started imposing fines, for example. example in Lithuania, Hungary, Poland and Portugal. In Portugal, the Autoridade da Concorrência also published in September a discussion paper and a guide to best practices for companies on the subject of competition law in the labor market.
  • In mid-June of this year, a committee of the Canadian Parliament called on the Canadian government to amend the Canadian Competition Act because the Competition Bureau was unable to sanction collusion between three Canadian supermarket operators. regarding the end of COVID-19 bonuses paid to employees. .
  • At the end of March 2021, the Brazilian competition authority, CADE, had opened antitrust investigations against 30 companies in the healthcare sector for allegedly fixing wages and for exchanging information on the labor market sensitive to the labor market. competition, such as wages, salary adjustments and additional compensation.
  • It seems to be only a matter of time until the European Commission and the German Bundeskartellamt catch up by also launching concrete investigations in this area and carrying out raids at dawn (European Commission and the Bundeskartellamt have so far only concluded agreements in the human resources sector in the cartel cases of pre-insulated pipes and TV studios as appendices to more extensive cartel agreements).

Antitrust assessment at a glance

Commissioner Vestager recently described agreements between competitors in labor markets as a “buyer’s cartel” with “a very direct effect on individuals, as well as on competition”. It is therefore worth considering how European competition law has dealt with such agreements to date and how they are currently assessed under competition law.

Antitrust law also applies in the labor market

EU antitrust law does not exempt the labor market as it is in principle applicable to all agreements and concerted practices between companies. However, there is a specific labor market restriction of the applicability of the ban on cartels (art. 101 TFEU) to employees. According to the case law of the European Court of Justice (“ECJ”), employees are excluded from the scope of art. 101 TFEU because they do not constitute companies but are incorporated into them. Therefore, agreements between unions (being an association of employees) are also not subject to antitrust legislation. In addition, the antitrust law does not cover collective agreements.

Market definition

The relevant product market is the labor market, on which companies compete for their (future) employees. The determining factor in defining this market is the interchangeability of the workforce from the point of view of companies as employers. It should be noted that companies from completely different industries may be competitors here. It does not matter whether firms compete in downstream markets for the products they manufacture.

But how far can this market be geographically? Here, it is above all necessary to take into account the qualifications of the employees or the requirement for specific training. The higher these requirements, the larger the geographic market to be defined, as the company will have to consider recruiting more distant collaborators as the quality requirements increase. However, this is limited on the one hand by real factors such as the location of the industry, language and possibly the mobility of workers. On the other hand, legal factors such as the requirement for residence permits and visas may also have an impact on market definition.

Agreements prohibited in the personnel sector

Not only current antitrust proceedings in the EU, but also past cases in the US show that problematic HR deals can arise, especially in the form of no-poaching and wage fixing deals.

The US antitrust authorities’ Antitrust Guidance for HR Professionals illustrates the importance of this area: it declares that wage settlements and non-solicitation agreements are in themselves breaches punishable by imprisonment under US antitrust law. This should be a particular warning to companies with ties to the United States, especially in the context of the aforementioned Department of Justice announcement to prioritize the review of resource competition restrictions. human beings in the future.

No-poaching agreements

There are two types of no-poaching agreements. The two have in common that they are agreements between employers in which companies form a sort of non-aggression pact with respect to their respective workforce. They differ in that some clauses only prohibit employer-initiated solicitation, while others even prohibit employment where contact was initiated by an employee request.

However, both types of no-poaching agreements are considered equally problematic under antitrust law, as they can in principle restrict competition for labor. However, this does not apply without exception: in individual cases, no-poaching agreements may be included as complementary agreements to an otherwise compliant contract, such as a business takeover (which is called “ancillary restriction”). Here, no-poaching agreements ensure the transfer of know-how and value from the target, of which the workforce is an integral part, and are therefore exempt from the application of antitrust law.

Exchange of information regarding salaries and other sensitive information on competition

Another type of offense which has been the subject of antitrust proceedings, for example in Hungary and Lithuania, is the fixing of wages. It should be noted that not only wage agreements as such can be classified as sensitive to competition, but also – analogously to sales price agreements in sales markets – wage components or ranges. salaries. For example, the Bundeskartellamt and the French Competition Authority have already imposed fines on the exchange of weekend and holiday bonuses (although ancillary to more extensive agreements).

Regarding the exchange of information between companies, the following principle should be applied: the more up-to-date the information and the more frequent the exchange, the more likely it is that the competition authorities will assume a restriction of competition by object. According to ECJ case law, even unilateral disclosure of competitively sensitive information may be sufficient.

“Significant extent” and individual exemption

If it turns out that an agreement restricts competition, it should in principle be examined on a case-by-case basis whether the restriction of competition is also appreciable and, if so, whether it is exempted from the prohibition on agreements. restrictive on the basis of efficiency gains under Article 101 (3) TFEU.

In recent case law (concerning Expedia), the Court of Justice assumed that restrictions of competition by object always restrict competition to an appreciable extent. In supply markets, agreements fixing prices are generally classified as restrictions by object. Whether this principle can be applied analogously to wage setting in demand side competition has to be considered on a case-by-case basis. In its Bank of Budapest decision, the ECJ rightly clarified that the concept of restriction of competition by object must be interpreted restrictively.

Outlook

The latest statements by Commissioner Vestager give reason to suppose that the European Commission is probably already targeting a specific labor market case and will soon start antitrust proceedings in order to set an example. Therefore, the uncertainties in the application of EU antitrust law to agreements in the human resources sector should not obscure the fact that the subject is now at the center of the concerns of antitrust authorities.

In addition, COVID19 has caused a backlog of antitrust raids at dawn. Commissioner Vestager has therefore announced a series of searches (coordinated at the international level) by her authority for the coming months by the antitrust authorities in this area. In particular, they should place an emphasis on the human resources department when reviewing their antitrust compliance management systems (see our article here for more information).

Previous City Utilities of Springfield explains how to save money freezing temperatures are coming
Next Synchrony launches one-of-a-kind program in Stamford to prepare disadvantaged youth for the digital economy